Finding a Good Model for Business in China
Cliff Cobb
Robert Schalkenbach Foundation
The United States has the largest economy in the world. As
a result, many ideas coming from the U.S. are given more respect
than they deserve. This is particularly true in professional
fields such as economics, law, and management. Many students
believe they are learning only technical skills when they study
these subjects from American textbooks or at American universities,
but they are also being taught a hidden set of ideas that may be
very dangerous.
I first became aware of the threat posed by American
intellectual culture when I traveled through Asia twenty years
ago. Almost everywhere, I found a desire among young people
to imitate the West. They wanted to be modern. What
they failed to understand was that they wanted to follow a group of
people who are wandering without direction. The intellectual
leaders of the West are lost in every field except the development
of new technology. In any field that requires a sense of
purpose, that asks how society should function or how a new
technology will be beneficial to society, there is only
confusion. When I understood this twenty years ago, I
returned to the U.S. with the hope of changing the ideas that
American intellectuals are teaching the rest of the world.
Now I am convinced that the only hope lies in other countries, such
as China.
The source of this intellectual crisis in Western thought lies
in a choice that was made over a century ago in philosophy.
The choice was to emphasize text over context and analysis over
synthesis. The method chosen teaches people to break the
world apart but provides no guidance about how to put it back
together. Western thought is good at examining a single
event, but not its relations to surrounding events. The basis
assumption is that the world can be divided into component parts,
just like a machine, and each part can be studied separately.
In practice, this means researchers believe they can make valid
predictions about future events simply by carefully observing the
individual parts of a system. This idea is dangerous because
it neglects the health of the system as a whole. Rather
than trying to explain in abstract terms what that means, I am
going to talk about the problems resulting from this approach to
knowledge as it faces the student of business. Specifically,
I am going to explain briefly why the management theories of three
popular American thinkers have failed to perform as expected.
Then I will offer the ideas of three visionaries who understood the
importance of whole systems.
THREE THEORIES OF BUSINESS SUCCESS—AND THEIR FLAWS
Peter Drucker and the productivity crisis
The first case I want to consider is Peter Drucker, the man who
is credited by some with inventing the modern discipline of
management. Much of what Drucker says is true at the level of
individual companies. For example, he wisely recognizes that
business needs a guiding spirit that is larger than making a
profit. Both managers and workers need inspiration, not just
financial success. I applaud Drucker for emphasizing that
point.
However, I also criticize Drucker's approach to
management. The premise that underlies his philosophy is that
entrepreneurship and the innovation of individual firms are the
sources of productivity growth and capital formation. That
emphasis on entrepreneurship comes from Joseph Schumpeter, one of
Drucker's professors. This view is not hard to
understand. It fits with common sense and direct
evidence.
In fact, the Schumpterian theory of economic dynamism that
Drucker adopted would be hard to discredit except for the fact that
it offers no explanation for one simple fact: the rate of
productivity rises and falls in an economy without any apparent
connection to changes taking place within individual
companies. Something else is at work. Productivity is
not primarily the result of the management of individual
companies. There are larger, strategic issues that are simply
left out of the model from which Drucker starts. But Drucker
has no theory of the whole economy. He is simply describing
the parts. When the system as a whole breaks down and
productivity stops rising, he must resort to ad hoc
explanations—which is an indication that he has no theory at
all. In a 1981 article, entitled 'Toward the next
economics,' Drucker proposed some of the elements that would
be needed for an adequate theory, but he recognized that his own
formulations could not account for the problems of the American
economy. Since any management theory should provide means of
raising productivity, I would suggest that this flaw raises some
doubts about the overall validity of Drucker's model.
Edward Deming and the collapse of the Japanese economy
The second business leader I wish to discuss is W. Edwards
Deming. Throughout the 1980s, American businesses faced
severe competition from Japan. Year after year, the balance of
payments deficit of the U.S. grew, and the dollar declined in
value. During that decade, many business authors tried to
explain the source of the American problems in terms of the
differences in management style in Japan and the U.S. For
example, Japanese companies operate on the basis of teamwork, so
American writers encouraged companies to copy the Japanese in that
respect.
In 1986, Deming published Out of the Crisis and changed
the discussion. In that book, Deming describes how he first
went to American companies in the 1950s with his statistical
methods of quality control, which would enable them to control
costs by reducing defects. The American companies were too
proud to listen. So, Deming went to Japan, where companies
such as Honda took his ideas seriously. As a result, Japanese
companies became more cost-effective in their production and other
operations. This experience became the basis for claiming
that the Deming method was responsible for Japanese manufacturing
companies out-performing American ones.
There is certainly value in the Deming method, and it continues
to be taught in American business schools. It is, however,
one technique among many others of value in managing an
enterprise. It was treated as the key to Japanese success and
American failure only because of timing. If Deming had
published his book ten years earlier or ten years later, it would
have had little impact. At the time, however, it seemed to
explain the problems of American business.
The appeal of the Deming way diminished rapidly after the
Japanese economy crashed in 1991. If Deming' methods were the
source of Japanese growth and prosperity, why had they suddenly
ceased to work? The answer is that statistical quality
control was never the source of Japanese success, nor was the
failure to apply Deming's principles the cause of failure among
American businesses. Productivity grew rapidly in the U.S. in
the 1990s, but there is no reason to believe that adoption of
Deming's philosophy was the cause. As in case of Drucker and
his failure to explain productivity changes, there is nothing wrong
with the Deming approach within a narrow context. However, it
cannot explain what happened to the Japanese economy or why
productivity among U.S. businesses rose again after 1994.
Tom Peters and the difficulty of finding mission or purpose
In 1982, Tom Peters and Robert Waterman published In Search
of Excellence, which attributed high productivity to the
characteristics of individual companies. By the time he wrote
Thriving on Chaos in 1987, Peters had changed his
mind. 'There are no excellent companies,' he
said. He had to say that. Most of the companies
profiled in the first book were no longer performing above
average. In other words, the original theory was a
failure. The success of the companies in the first book
appeared to be almost random.
A few years later, however, Peters came back with another book,
Liberation Management. This remains one of the best
books on management I've seen. It offers two steps to good
management that are relatively easy to say, but extremely difficult
to do. The two steps are 1) develop a clear mission or
purpose for the organization and 2) give people a chance to
experiment and fail. By being allowed to fail, workers will
find new ways to succeed, not just for themselves, but for the
whole organization. If people are working toward the same
goal, which is only possible if the mission is clear, they will
have the spirit that Drucker believes is important, and they do not
need close supervision.
But where does the vision come from that drives effective
organizations? That is a question that Peters does not
ask. It comes from the culture, not simply the
organization. Although individual companies can capture
some unusual quality that enhances performance, in the long run all
companies are drawing on the same cultural sources for their
inspiration. Thus, it is good business to care about
the whole of society, not just the bottom line. If businesses
operate as if the larger culture is unimportant, they will destroy
the ground they stand on. Because Peters, like Drucker and
Deming, focuses only on the individual business, he cannot see that
the source of value and spirit lies in the system a whole.
THREE SOURCES OF INSPIRATION
The lesson that I derive from Drucker and Peters, though not so
much from Deming, is that the effective business leader will
inspire others to go beyond themselves. In that respect, the
good business leader is no different from a good religious
leader.
If that is the case, then the education of business managers
must include more than the standard courses in accounting, finance,
management, and other technical skills. It needs to include
courses in the humanities that will give business leaders the tools
from which to develop the vision that will make them good
managers. This was a tradition in American universities until
recently, but now it is rapidly dying, as universities have lost
their own sense of purpose.
In China and other countries where students are exposed to
American ideas, I believe it would be of value for business
managers to learn about the ideas of the rare people who have had
holistic visions of social transformation. Not only are their
ideas important in themselves, they also offer a model of
organizational vision. I could begin with Marx, but I assume that
you are already familiar with his ideas. Instead, I will
discuss three American and British visionaries who have helped
redefine the boundaries of thought as it applies to
economics.
Henry Ford
I begin with Henry Ford, the man who developed the first
assembly line for mass production of cars. He was not a grand
theorist, but he did have a vision that related to the economy as a
whole. His idea was simple. He paid his workers a wage
high enough to buy the cars he was making. In a sense,
he was naïve. His idea makes sense only if every company
follows the same plan. His vision was on a macro scale (the
entire economy), but his action was still at the micro level
(within the individual firm).
Nevertheless, there is a hint in Ford's philosophy that could
help all businesses in China, if his idea were to be applied at the
national level, not just by individual companies. At present,
foreign trade accounts for about 15% of the Chinese economy.
Although that is a source of strength, it also makes China
dependent on its trade partners, much as Japan has been dependent
on the United States. As the Japanese say, 'If the U.S.
catches cold, Japan sneezes.' The best way for China to
avoid that sort of dependency would be to strengthen the internal
market for Chinese goods. Henry Ford's philosophy explains
how to do that: pay wages high enough for workers to buy the
products. Henry Ford did not offer a theory of how to manage
the economy to make that happen. But he did have the vision
to see that cutting costs by paying workers as little as
possible was not the way to achieve prosperity.
Henry George
The second visionary I want to mention was Henry George.
Half a century before Henry Ford, he had already developed a theory
that explained how to keep wages high and maintain national
prosperity. That theory was based on a macroeconomic analysis
rather than the observation of individual firms. George
argued that low wages, cyclical unemployment, and changes in
productivity could be traced to a single source: the hoarding and
misuse of land, particularly of the most valuable urban
locations. Perhaps more importantly, he realized that the
dense economic interactions that take place in cities are not
merely additive; rather, they are multiplicative. He saw that
synergy or interaction is the true engine of economic development,
and if institutions interfere with it, the spirit of progress will
be retarded or destroyed. Although George would have agreed
with Drucker and Peters that the human spirit is ultimately
responsible for productivity, that spirit is not found
'inside' individuals. Instead, it can only be found
in the relationships among people. If land is used in ways
that interfere with those relationships, then it will reduce both
spirit and productivity.
Although George had an almost mystical view of the economic
system, it had very down-to-earth implications for both market and
socialist planning. If land is privately owned, businesses
are trained to value it at its historic price rather than its
current value. But that means profits can be made on paper
simply by buying land. Since it is easier to make money by
holding land than by producing goods, businesses shift their
investments toward speculative property management. The
result is a casino economy with lots of mergers and acquisitions
and high interest rates. Companies are then expected to show
rapid returns on investment, which destroys their capacity for
long-term investment and planning. Real investment outside of
the real estate sector declines until the bubble
bursts. In addition, public spending rises to cover the
costs of building the infrastructure such as roads, water supply,
and schools for cities that are expanding rapidly into the
countryside.
If land is publicly owned, as it is in China, all of the same
consequences will happen unless it is leased at a rate that
represents its changing value. The wasteful use of urban land in
China is one of the greatest obstacles to its development.
That will continue unless businesses are required to take account
of the rising value of land each year, instead of just once when
they acquire it. If factories are allowed to occupy space in
the center of cities, they will displace commercial and
professional uses, to the detriment of productivity. What
Henry George showed, and what business leaders in every country
need to recognize, is that the mispricing and misuse of land has
systemic effects that harm the entire economy.
John Maynard Keynes
The third systemic thinker was John Maynard Keynes. It is
significant that Keynes never thought of himself as an
economist. He was a philosopher at heart. He devoted
his attention to solving practical problems because he was pulled
into serving the British government. His solution was to turn
the inherited principles of sound economic management upside
down. Instead of looking for ways to increase productivity,
he asked how to promote consumption. Paradoxically, by
ignoring productivity, he showed how to increase it. Instead
of treating money as a superficial veil over the real economy of
physical goods and services, Keynes said that money itself
represents the social reality of trust. In the process, he
prescribed a solution that restored the production of physical
goods and services. By rejecting common sense and embracing
paradox, Keynes showed how to solve the problems of a complex
system.
Peter Drucker says very directly that Keynes was wrong.
Like many other people trained in economics, Drucker believes that
Keynes provided a solution that was valid only for one particular
crisis. But, as I suggested, Drucker knows that economic
theory is faulty, and he has no valid theory of productivity.
So who is right? My own vote is for Keynes.
Whether or not he is right in every detail is not important.
The lesson we need to learn from Keynes is to look at whole
systems, following his example of looking at the whole
economy. Above all, he taught us to question our most basic
assumptions. We should be looking, he might have said, for
the one variable that controls the health of the whole
system. Until we can conceive of the system as a whole, we
will continue to wander in darkness. Thus, what Keynes taught
was not merely a new way of thinking of economics, but a new way of
understanding any complex system.
CONCLUSION
I began by suggesting that the U.S. is conquering the world
through its universities and textbooks. I want to end by
saying that that is not inevitable. The question for
countries such as China is whether you will pay attention to our
blind leaders or to our forgotten visionaries.
I have discussed the ideas of three men (Drucker, Deming, and
Peters) who have been influential in the U.S. and whose books have
been read in other countries. Although they have been
considered experts, their ideas have validity only within a small
domain. Their theories are based on the behavior of
individuals. They may explain how to solve the problems
within a business, they cannot solve the problems within the larger
environment faced by business. Their method looks at parts,
and as a result, they cannot reveal the context or whole
system. They are not the visionaries they imagine themselves
to be.
The true visionaries of the West have met the common fate of
those who resist the trends within their own culture. George,
Keynes, and, to a lesser extent, Ford, were visionaries because
they understood that systems have a life of their own. One
might say that they applied a philosophy of organism to the field
of economics. By doing so, they overcame the assumptions in
prevailing individualistic models.
My hope is that the future business leaders of China will
recognize the contradictions inherent in the dominant ideas of the
West. The textbooks from America project a smooth facade of a
society based on individualistic premises. But that façade is
cracking. Behind the surface is confusion, disarray, and
uncertainty. Western thinkers are searching for a way
forward in much the same way that Chinese thinkers are looking for
new answers. I have suggested today that the best thinkers in
the West are those with an organic-holistic model of social
interaction, economics, and management. Because holistic
models do not fit well with the mechanistic and individualistic
assumptions that prevail in the West, they have been largely
ignored at home. But that does not mean you should ignore
them. If you wish to learn from the West, I hope you will
heed our visionaries who represent a minority perspective.
That is where the true voice of positive change can be found.
|